Corporate Finance

Inhalt der englischen CF-Vorlesung

Inhalt der englischen CF-Vorlesung

Jasmin Brander

Jasmin Brander

Kartei Details

Karten 182
Sprache English
Kategorie Finanzen
Stufe Universität
Erstellt / Aktualisiert 10.11.2014 / 14.05.2024
Weblink
https://card2brain.ch/box/corporate_finance2
Einbinden
<iframe src="https://card2brain.ch/box/corporate_finance2/embed" width="780" height="150" scrolling="no" frameborder="0"></iframe>

7 // IPOs and SEOs

What are the direct and indirect costs of going public?

Direct Costs

Substantial administrative costs

Underwriting fee: Spread

The investment banks are allowed to buy the shares for less than the  offering price at which the shares are sold to investors

Indirect Costs

Underpricing

Investors who buy at the issue price on average realize very high returns over the following days.For IPOs these costs generally exceed all other issue costs

7 // IPOs and SEOs

A company’s first public issue of stock is seldom its last. As the firm grows, it is likely to make further issues of debt and equity (SEO = Seasoned Equity Offering). Public companies can issue securities in two possible ways.

Name and explain them.

General Cash Offers (USA)

  • Much the same procedure as when company first went public
  • "Shelf Registration" possible: it allows large companies to file a single registration statement covering financing plans for up to three years into the future. It then has the right but not the obligation to issue up to the stated amount.

Rights Issues (most other countries)

  • Instead of making an issue of stock to investors at large, companies sometimes give their existing shareholders the right of first refusal. Also known as  privileged subscription,  

7 // IPOs and SEOs - The IPO Market

Underpricing and the number of IPOs

Summarize the observations of Ritter (2012)

There are hot and cold issue periods (very cyclical! sometimes you should better wait)

  • After 2001, the number of IPOs remained on a much lower level than before, also in the years with high stock market returns.
  • The underpricing started to increase in the 1990s and peaked at the end of the 1990s during the tech bubble.
  • Not surprisingly, the aggregate money left on the table is highly correlated with underpricing and peaked at the end of the 1990s during the tech bubble (approx. USD 65 bn. left on the table in 1999 and 2000).
  • Until 2000, there were not only more IPOs in general, but also more IPOs of small firms.
  • Until 2000, the underpricing of smaller IPOs was in general larger, as of 2001 it became smaller than that of large IPOs.

7 // IPOs and SEOs - The IPO Market

Long-term performance of IPOs

Summarize the observations of Ritter (2012)

  • The 7,531 US IPOs taking place between 1980 and 2010 have a positive average return of 20.8% over the first three years after going public.
    • However, as compared to the stock market (CRSP value-weighted index) the IPO firms underperform by 19.7%.
    • As compared to a portfolio of size- and book-to-market matched firms, IPO firms underperform by 7.4%.
      -> BENCHMARKS are relevant! What did the market do?
  • Smaller IPOs perform worse than larger IPOs.
  • Venture Capital-backed IPOs perform better than non-VC-backed IPOs.
    • VC preselect good IPOs
    • VC monitor the companies - less agency costs
    • VC give advice - they have a lot of experience
  • Larger IPOs (>50mio sales), whether buyout-backed (bring private-made company back to public) or not, perform better than a portfolio sizeand book-to-market matched firms (by 3.9%). 

7 // IPOs and SEOs - Where have all the IPOs gone?

-> What are the two main and third new (Gao, Ritter & Zhu [2012]) explanations for the following?:

Drop in number of IPOs is pronounced for small firms

  • The low volume of IPOs in the last decade is even more pronounced when one takes into account the 117% increase in real GDP during the time period.
  • Small firm IPOs (with pre-issue annual sales of less than USD 50 m.) declined from 165 IPOs per year in 1980-2000 to 30 IPOs per year in 2001-2009.
  • Large company IPOs decreased from an annual average of 146 IPOs in 1980-2000 to 72 IPOs in 2001-2009

Public discussion:

  • The low level of IPOs this decade has generated much discussion among private company executives, stock exchange officials, policy-makers, and the financial press, as well as among venture capitalists and buyout firms that depend on an active IPO market for exits.
  • Concern that the lack of a vibrant IPO market could limit Gross Domestic Product (GDP) and employment growth.

 

  1. The Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002 (SOX), particularly Section 404
    • Imposes additional compliance costs on publicly traded firms. As a percentage of revenue, these costs have been especially large for small firms. Consistent with the SOX explanation for the decline in IPO activity, the decline in IPOs has been most pronounced among small firms.
  2. There might be a decline in the “ecosystem” of underwriters that focus on smaller firms and provide analyst coverage after a company has gone public:
    • There was a drop in bid-ask spreads associated with decimalization in 2001.
    • The U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission’s (SEC) Regulation FD (Fair Disclosure) in 2000 and the 2003 Global Settlement.
    • The decline in bid-ask spreads and other regulatory changes may have reduced the incentive of market makers to have affiliated analysts cover a stock.
    • Consistently, Jegadeesh and Kim (2010) report that both the number of firms covered and the number of sell-side analysts peaked in 2002 and then declined
  3. There is an on-going change in the economy that has reduced the profitability of small companies, whether public or private
    • This explanation is based on the technological determinants of the optimal scale of the firm in a dynamic environment, where profitable growth opportunities may be lost if they are not quickly seized.
    • Many small firms can create greater operating profits by selling out in a trade sale (being acquired by a firm in the same or a related industry) rather than operating as an independent firm.
    • Earnings will be higher as part of a larger organization that can realize economies of
      scope and bring new technology to market faster.

7 // IPOs and SEOs - Where have all the IPOs gone?

Name the 3 evidences that the speed of technological innovation has increased to the benefit of larger firms (compliant with the explanation of Gao, Ritter & Zhu [2012])

  • Sorescu, Chandy, and Prabhu (2003) and Sood and Tellis (2005) document that in recent years, most new technologies have been introduced by large firms.
  • The pace of technological change has increased over time, placing small firms at a disadvantage because they lack the resources to quickly take advantage of new technology.
  • The internet has made comparison shopping easier for consumers (Goldmanis, Hortacsu, Syverson, and Emre, 2010). With reduced search costs, there is more of a “winner take all” tendency. Thus, in some sectors, the profitmaximizing size of firms has increased, and the number of firms with positive economic profits has decreased.

7 // IPOs and SEOs - Where have all the IPOs gone?

Are SOX costs really the problem?

And what are further empirical findings?

  • The downtrend in small firm profitability (not only IPOs) began before SOX (2002).
  • Among small firm IPOs, the percentage that are unprofitable in the three years after going public has increased from 58% in 1980-2000 to 73% in 2001-2009. In contrast, for large company IPOs there has been no downtrend in post-IPO
  • profitability.
  • The long-run returns earned by investors on small company IPOs have been poor from 1980 to 2009, with the relative performance of small company IPOs particularly disappointing after 2000.
  • Inconsistent with the regulatory overreach hypothesis, relatively few U.S. firms have chosen to go public abroad.
  • For the firms that do go public, the fraction that are acquired or make acquisitions within a few years of going public has increased over time.

7 // IPOs and SEOs - Why is there underpricing?

Name three reasons for underprcing

Underpricing compensates for risk (Ritter, 1984):
– Riskier IPOs will be underpriced by more than less-risky (information-asymmetry etc.) IPOs.
– If the proportion of IPOs that represent risky stocks increases, there should be greater average underpricing.
– Risk can reflect either technological or valuation uncertainty.
 

Realignment of incentives (Ljungqvist and Wilhelm, 2003):
– Managers are willing to leave money on the table, especially during the 1999-2000 period for the following reasons:  
- lower CEO ownership
- fewer IPOs containing secondary shares
- increased ownership fragmentation (one owner could bargain better than many)
- more “friends and family” share allocations

Analyst coverage and spinning (Loughran and Ritter, 2004):
– As issuers placed more importance on hiring a lead underwriter with a highly ranked (and bullish) analyst to cover the firm, they became less concerned about avoiding underwriters with a reputation for excessive underpricing. In the future, they would profit from that relationship and get shares in other IPOs.
– The more that issuing firms see analyst coverage as important, the more they are willing to pay these costs.
– Beginning in the 1990s, underwriters started to set up personal brokerage accounts for venture capitalists and the executives of issuing firms in order to allocate hot IPOs to them (“spinning”).
– The purpose of these side payments is to influence the issuer’s choice of lead underwriter: These payments create an incentive to seek, rather than avoid, underwriters with a reputation for severe underpricing. 

7 // IPOs and SEOs - Explaining the "New Issues Puzzle"

Look at the graphs / table and state the main results of the research of Hoechle & Schmid (2010)

  • IPO firms significantly underperform over the first year after going public, while there is virtually no underperformance thereafter.
  • The finding of an IPO underperformance based on a Carhart type four-factor model contradicts prior research.
  • These studies however focus on longer time horizons of usually three to five years over which the underperformance is in fact substantially weaker.
  • When besides the four Carhart risk factors (market excess return, size factor, value/growth factor, and momentum factor) various firm characteristics related to the IPO market environment, firm leverage and liquidity, firm valuation,
  • corporate diversification strategy, and investments are accounted for, there is no significant difference between the performance of IPO firms and that of nonissuing (mature) companies.
  • As in the case of IPOs, there is a large literature documenting that stocks of common stock issuers (SEOs) subsequently underperform non-issuers which are matched based on size and book-to-market by approximately 40%-60% over 3 to 5 years (Loughran and Ritter, 1995; Spiess and Affleck-Graves, 1995).
  • Using a sample of more than 7,000 seasoned equity (and debt) issues from 1964 to 1995, Eckbo, Masulis, and Norli (2000) document that issuer underperformance reflects lower systematic risk exposure for issuing firms
  • relative to the matched firms.
  • A consistent explanation is that, as equity issuers lower leverage, their exposures to unexpected inflation and default risks decrease, thus decreasing their stocks’ expected returns relative to matched firms.
  • Equity issues also significantly increase stock liquidity (turnover), again lowering expected returns relative to non-issuers.
  • Eckbo, Masulis, and Norli (2000): The “new issue puzzle” is explained by a failure of the matched-firm technique to provide a proper control for risk.

8 // Mergers & Acquisitions - Merger Activity and Merger Waves

What and when were the three merger waves exactly?

 

  •  1960s: “conglomerate merger wave”
    • Aim was to acquire firms in unrelated businesses to become large conglomerates (big company with many unrelated activities) to diversify and reduce risk
      • But diversification is sth the shareholders can do on their own
  • 1980s: hostile “bust-up” takeovers
    • Idea was not to build up a larger firm but to buy a competitor and sell the assets and use that money to pay for the acquisition price -> simply to get rid of a competitor
  • 1990s: strategic/global mergers in related areas
    • Takeover as a mean to get access to international markets. If e.g. you are German, you can buy a Swiss firm to get access to the Swiss market

8 // Mergers & Acquisitions - Merger Arbitrage

In 1999/2000, Microsoft took over Visio by a stock swap: 0,45 Microsoft for 1 Visio share

Microsoft was trading at ~$100, Visio at ~$30, thus Microsoft paid $45 - $15 too much! And the Visio share immediately jumped up to $45

This is one of the most consistent patterns in corporate finance and overservable in almost all takeovers!

-> Why would an acquirer pay so much (too much) for a target?

Economic reason for acquirer to pay so much for a target:

The target firm is unique and thus has a monopoly on the market. Accordingly, it sets the price way too high to maximize it's profits (VWL).

Further, the acquirer has to make an offer that seems reasonable to the current owners 'cause they might be aware of how much money the acquirer can make out of their shares. If the price isn't high enough, the owners of the target wouldn't be willing to sell the firm, they would wait

8 // Mergers & Acquisitions - Merger Arbitrage

How can merger arbitrage be conducted (Pfizer example)?

What are the risk factors?

Most important success factor for MA strategies: Does the merger take place?

If it does not, all the gain will be lost! (Honeywell case)

  • The position and conduct of the management of the target firm
  • Potential anti-takeover measures put in place by the target firm's management (e.g., poison pills, shareholder rights plans, classified boards with staggered terms, etc.)
  • The willingness of shareholders to sell their shares for the offered price
  • The regulatory authorities (e.g., Federal Trade Commission (FTC) in the US, Weko (Wettbewerskommission) in Switzerland, Bundeskartellamt in Germany), you must be familiar with the law!

Additional risk factors

  • A successful (diversified) implementation of MA strategies requires enough mergers
  • “merger spreads” have to be large enough on average to be able to overcompensate the losses from failed transactions
  • Merger waves: bear markets and an unstable economic environment negatively affect the number of announced transactions and the success probability

8 // Mergers & Acquisitions - Merger Arbitrage

Explain:

  • Poison Pills
  • (Board with) staggered terms

Poison Pill

A strategy used by corporations to discourage hostile takeovers. With a poison pill, the target company attempts to make its stock less attractive to the acquirer. There are two types of poison pills: 

  1. A "flip-in" allows existing shareholders (except the acquirer) to buy more shares at a discount.
  2. A "flip-over" allows stockholders to buy the acquirer's shares at a discounted price after the merger.

(Board with) staggered Terms

The board has people with different terms, thus the board cannot be replaced simulaneously

8 // Mergers & Acquisitions - Who gains from mergers?

Event Studies (s. picture)

What was found by Andrade, Mitchell, and Stafford (2001) when they researched who the winner in a merger is?

What about the difference between payment in stocks and no stocks?

.

8 // Mergers & Acquisitions - Mergers and Corporate Governance

Considering Coporate Governance, which firms do better in takeovers?

Those firms in which managers are protected do worse in a takeover

-> there might be a lot of personal and prestige reasons instead of value-maximization for the firm and the shareholders  (e.g. empire building or doing a merger in a field where manager is an expert so he won't be fired etc.)

 

picture: indices measure the anti-takeover provisions (the higher the index, the worse the corporate governance)

9 // Corporate Governance - Corporate Governance Mechanisms

Define Corporate Governance

.

9 // Corporate Governance - Corporate Governance Mechanisms

What about the other stakeholders? Is the sole focus on shareholder value incongruous?

.

9 // Corporate Governance - Corporate Governance Mechanisms

How can Corporate Governance benefit shareholders? And is it recognized by them?

careful: the results of the McKinsey-survey are only statements, not measurement results!

9 // Corporate Governance - Corporate Governance Mechanisms

Mention the 9 corporate governance mechanisms that may be used as substitutes or complements

Class focuses on the first two

 

remarks:

Threat of takeover: if you waste a lot of money your share price plummets and you're likely to be taken over and fired

High debt levels: without debt, you only "have to" pay dividends, but you can just as well use that money for corporate jets etc. Debt, on the other side, HAS to be paid back!

9 // Corporate Governance - Corporate Governance Mechanisms

Incentive Schemes

What good can incentive schemes do generally? What is a limitation?

 

Greater pay for performance may align managerial interests with shareholders’:

  • The larger the fraction of the equity of the firm the manager owns, the costlier the private consumption perks will be for her (ex-post).
  • By making pay contingent on performance, the manager is more likely to be diligent and to take the right (NPV maximizing) projects (ex-ante).

Typically, one cannot observe managerial effort directly but by a noisy signal like profits. One has to make payments contingent on this measure.

Trade-off between risk aversion and provision of incentives: Making pay sensitive to profits provides incentives for the manager to exert more effort.

Limitation
However, since part of the profits is outside the control of the manager, you subject her pay to noise, and she will demand a higher expected pay even though she didn't do anything for it!

9 // Corporate Governance - Corporate Governance Mechanisms

Incentive Schemes

There is evidence for a link between the introduction of incentive plans and company performance

Name and explain three possible explanations

  1. Incentive plans motivate managers to make better decisions
  2. “Managers might have influence over their own compensation and use this power to obtain more performance-based pay in advance of anticipated stock price increases” (e.g., Yermack, 1997).
    • Managers can decide the starting point of an option -> they choose a low point before an increase so that the value of the option will increase
  3. Backdating (e.g., Heron and Lie, 2007)
    • Even if you're already in the future, you can negotiate the starting point to be some time ago

9 // Corporate Governance - Corporate Governance Mechanisms

Incentive Schemes

There is evidence that managers are rewarded for “luck” (Bertrand and Mullainathan, 2000):

  • Example: Compensation of managers of the oil industry increases with increases in the price of oil. When the price of oil declines their compensation does not seem to decline.
  • More generally, CEO pay responds to “luck”:
    • CEO pay is equally sensitive to a “lucky dollar” than to a “general dollar” (sensitivity refers to the % change in CEO compensation as a result of a 1% change in a variable of interest)
    • But, in firms with better governance (firms with large shareholders, firms in which the large shareholder sits on the board, and firms in which CEO tenure is short) show the same sensitivity to a “general dollar” but smaller sensitivity to a “lucky dollar”
  • Evidence of managerial opportunism only in firms with poor governance. In firms with good governance compensation responds less to luck!

-> Name three possible solutions!

.

9 // Corporate Governance - Corporate Governance Mechanisms

Incentive Schemes

Bebuchuk and Fried (2005) did research on the growth of executive pay in the US. What are their main findings?

Both cash and equity payments increased -> total compensation increased!

9 // Corporate Governance - Corporate Governance Mechanisms

Incentive Schemes

What are the five possible reasons for the increase in compensation?

.

9 // Corporate Governance - Empirical Evidence

What subsets of provisions does the G-Index include?

  1. Classified board
  2. Limitation on amending bylaws (Statuten)
  3. Limitation on amending the charter ([Gründungs]urkunde)
  4. Supermajority to approve a merger
  5. Golden Parachute
  6. Poison Pill

 

-> the more such things you have, the higher your index and the lower your value because the worse your corporate governance

9 // Corporate Governance - Empirical Evidence

What is there to say about reverse causation, G-index and valuation?

  • A common “reverse causation” story in the corporate governance literature is the possibility that a firm with lower firm valuation will tend to limit shareholder rights, adopting more G-Index provisions in order to insulate the firm from hostile takeovers (see, e.g., Lehn, Patro, and Zhao 2006).
    • As a result, the documented correlation between low firm valuation and the GIndex, according to this story, might be at least in part due to reverse causation.
  • Cremers and Ferrell (2011) examine whether a firm’s valuation, as measured by that firm’s lagged Tobin’s Q ( Kurs-Substanzwert-Verhältnis handelt. Ein Wert kleiner 1 zeigt eine Unterbewertung, ein Wert größer 1 eine Überbewertung an), helps to explain changes in a firm’s G-Index and E-index scores (controlling also for other firm characteristics).
    • The results show that the explanatory power of lagged Q is relatively weak and economically minor indicating that the problem of reverse causality is unlikely to be responsible for the positive relation between governance and firm value

-> As the effect of lagged Q on corporate governance is substantially smaller than the effect of corporate governance on Q, reverse causality is unlikely to be responsible for the significant negative relation between Q and governance.

9 // Corporate Governance - Empirical Evidence

What about poison pills?

  • The year of the dramatic increase in the incidence of poison pills, 1985, was the same year as the seminal case of Moran v. Household International, which judicially validated the poison pill for the first time.
  • Cremers and Ferrell (2011) test the hypothesis whether the legal validity of the poison pill after 1985 instigated a significant shift in power from shareholders to the board of directors.
    • As the use of the governance provisions in the G-Index is largely at the board’s discretion, this would imply that the G-Index, poison pills, and classified boards have a more significant negative effect on firm valuation post-1985 relative to pre-1985
      • The governance provisions in the G-Index could affect the likelihood of receiving a successful takeover bid and thus a significant takeover premium.
      • If the G-Index is negatively associated with firm value by reducing the likelihood of an attractive takeover, then the negative effects of a higher G-Index should be particularly powerful when a firm happens to be in an industry experiencing “high” levels of takeover activity, relative to firms in the same industry with lower G-Index scores and relative to firms with the same G-Index score but in an industry which was experiencing “low” levels of takeover activity in that year.

-> As one can see on the picture: without the poison pills, the G-index is not significant anymore!

-> The poison pill is one of the most important ingredients of corporate governance (the results are mainly driven by it). If you have a poison pill, you cannot easily be taken over and thus can waste more money...

Exercise 1 // Investment Project Evaluation

How can investment projects be classified?

  • Independent
  • Mutually exclusive (you can EITHER do one or the other)
  • Contingent (you can only do B if you do A first)

Exercise 1 // Investment Project Evaluation

What does the Capital Budgeting Process look like?

.

Exercise 1 // Investment Project Evaluation

ANNUTIES

Solve the example

.

Exercise 1 // Financial Modeling

What are the objectives of financial modeling?

.

Exercise 1 // Financial Modeling

What are the risk factors of financial modeling?

  • complexity (start with small question -> model starts growing)
  • size (large data)
  • understanding of the problem (esp. as a consultant from the outside)
  • potential impact (on course of company)
  • urgency of results (you barely have enough time)
  • people involved (many)

Exercise 1 // Financial Modeling

What is the general approach to financial modeling?

.

Exercise 1 // Financial Modeling - Design Phase

How should the dataflow in the worksheet look like?

What are the golden rules for the design phase?

.

And for the Build Phase: KISS -> Keep It Smart and Simple

Exercise 1 // Risk Analysis

What types of analyses do we know?

  • Sensitivity (analyzes effects of changes in sales, costs etc. on project), e.g. Otoboai Scooter case
  • Scenario (project analysis given particular combination of assumptions)
  • Simulation (estimates probabilities of different outcomes)
  • Break Even (level of sales [or other variable] at which project breaks even)

Exercise 1 // Risk Analysis

Break Even Analysis // EXAM

What's the difference between NPV break-even and accounting break-even?

Solve the example

.

Exercise 1 // Risk Analysis

Operating Leverage // EXAM

What is operating leverage? Show the formulas to calculate the degree of operating leverage!

  • Inside factor for profitability
  • Systematic risk
  • Overall risk (volatility) of a firm and the systematic risk of common stock of a firm are positively associated with the degree of operating leverage, or negatively associated with the firms level of variable costs

Implications: Capacity planning/forecasting is crucial!

 

Exercise 2 // Real Options

  • When are NPV and option value the same?
  • When do NPV and option value diverge?

.

Exercise 2 // Real Options

There are two extra sources of value if investement decision may be deferred:

  1. Time Value of Money of deferred expenditure
  2. Decision not to invest when circumstances have changed

Explain source 1

.

Exercise 2 // Real Options

There are two extra sources of value if investement decision may be deferred:

  1. Time Value of Money of deferred expenditure
  2. Decision not to invest when circumstances have changed

Explain source 2

.